In future research, we would refine our study by separating out imports from
developing and developed countries. We also would separate various impacts
of imported inputs by classifying imported intermediate inputs and imports of
final competing goods to see how they affect firm performance in developing
economies. Furthermore, as suggested by Yahmed and Dougherty (2012), one
may look at the position of firm’s productivity in relation to the industry productivity frontier to provide a better measure of technological advance. In addition,
considering multiple product or multiple business functionality firms (e.g. firms
both import inputs and/or complete products for sales and produce products for
local and exporting markets), the effect of import penetration would vary across
different types of firms (Bernard, Redding and Schott 2011). Finally, the net benefit
of trade liberalization can be observed when we look at the impacts of imports, exports and across-industry effect simultaneously. This is another avenue for future
research
26 trang |
Chia sẻ: linhmy2pp | Ngày: 12/03/2022 | Lượt xem: 280 | Lượt tải: 0
Bạn đang xem trước 20 trang tài liệu Does rising import competition harm local firm productivity in less advanced economies? Evidence from the Vietnam’s manufacturing sector, để xem tài liệu hoàn chỉnh bạn click vào nút DOWNLOAD ở trên
s (fixed effect). However, one potential
problem of differencing is that it maymagnifymeasurement error;therefore, longer
differences should be used to reduce the impact of the measurement error.4
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
8 T. Doan et al.
In empirical analysis, we start with a baseline estimation of Equation (1) with
the ordinary least squares (OLS) and FE model for level data, and then with
time-differenced specifications (Equation 2).
lnVAijt = α + β1imp penj t + β2 lnKijt + β3 lnLijt
+β4ownershipij t + λt + eijt . (2)
This is a common parsimonious alternative (e.g. Edwards and Jenkins 2013;
Bloom, Draca, and Van Reenen, 2011; Bugamelli, Fabiani, and Sette 2010) to
estimate separate capital and labour coefficients for each of 128 separate industry
groups at four-digit level over the study period, or using a two-step approach
of regressing residuals from industry-specific production functions on import
penetrationmeasures. Due to the inclusion of industry fixed effects, the coefficients
on the import penetration measures are identified by within-industry (four-digit
level) variation over time for time-difference models. In this construction, there is
no within-industry variation in import penetration in any given year.
Direct estimation of Equation 2 may give biased estimates of the key parame-
ters of interest (β1) due to omitted variables that are correlated with both import
penetration and value added, or due to the endogeneity of factor inputs or import
penetration, where these covariates may respond to value added. Such biases may
result in upward estimates of positive (or negative) effects even no effects taking
place.
The endogenous choice of factor inputs is another potential source of en-
dogeneity bias. Firms may choose variable factor inputs in response to new in-
formation on their (possibly time varying) firm-specific productivity (λi). This
introduces an upward bias in the coefficients on variable inputs such as labour, and
a consequent downward bias on the capital coefficient (Griliches and Mairesse
1998). The degree of bias that this form of endogeneity causes to estimates of
import penetration effects is an empirical question.
There are several solutions to the endogeneity of inputs. The first is the IV ap-
proach. This method needs valid instruments that are correlated with endogenous
variables (input level choice, e.g. labour) but not correlated with firm outcome or
its residual (error terms). It is typically hard to find good instruments that satisfy
the conditions. Input prices (interest rate and/or wage rate) can be potential in-
struments, but input prices are often unavailable in data-sets or do not vary or do
not vary enough across firms. Even if there is a variation in input price, it may
account for market power in input markets or heterogeneity in quality of inputs,
e.g. worker quality that may invalidate the use of input price as an instrument
(Ackerberg, Caves, and Frazer 2006). Recently, some suggest using the approach
of Levinsohn and Petrin (2003), an extension of Olley and Pakes (1996),that uses
firm’s intermediate consumption to control for the endogeneity. However, there
are some disadvantages in these approaches such as identification and estima-
tion issues (see more detailed discussion in Ackerberg, Caves, and Frazer 2006,
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 9
and Wooldridge 2009). Due to the lack of valid instruments to address the endo-
geneity and lack of outperforming methods, we therefore apply the conventional
approach, the OLS and the FE to a Cobb–Douglas production function in this
paper to estimate TFP.
We rely on estimates that do not explicitly control for the endogeneity of factor
inputs, focusing instead on controlling for the potential endogeneity of import
penetration. Whereas firms are expected to endogenously adjust factor inputs in
response to annual changes in firm-specific productivity (λit), import penetration is
likely to respond to changes in overall productivity performance within industries.
The inclusion of industry fixed effects and industry-specific time controls the
influence of import firms targeting particular industries on the basis of average
industry productivity or relative productivity growth of industries over the sample
period. Imports may gravitate towards more profitable or higher mark-up sectors.
Imports may also be attracted to less competitive sectors to exploit their greater
competitive advantages. Therefore, there is potential reverse causality.
The import penetration (or import penetration growth as we use time-
differencing) variable is potentially endogenous and may be influenced by in-
ternational trade shocks in the last few decades such as China’s accession to the
WTO that resulted in Chinese export boom, and FTAs that Vietnam signed with
its key trade partners. Therefore, estimates from (1) and (2) may suffer from bias
due to endogeneity of import penetration.
Our identification strategy to deal with the endogeneity is to exploit the ex-
ogenous shocks to Vietnam’s imports. In the last decade, Vietnam signed many
FTAs with its key trade partners including an FTA agreement between China and
ASEAN of which Vietnam is a member.5 China’s accession to the WTO in 2001
may also have been a big shock to Vietnam’s imports. We make use of China’s
exports (to the world) as a potentially suitable instrument candidate for our iden-
tification strategy because China’s exports may meet two conditions for a good
instrument: (1) Vietnam’s imports and China’s exports may be correlated, and (2)
Vietnamese firm productivity is not directly correlated with China’s exports.
China’s export penetrationmay not be directly correlated with Vietnamese firm
productivity. Hence, we may model Vietnam’s import penetration as a function of
China’s exports, either in levels or changes as seen in Equations (3) and (4).
importj,t−m = f (CNexportj,t−m,Xj,t−m) (3)
importj,t−m = f (CNexportj,t−m,Xj,t−m) (4)
We also use lag length (m) to allow for reverse causality and firm dynamic
response to import competition in the production function estimation.
We shall exploit Chinese export growth as a source for instruments because
they capture the impact of China’s accession to theWTO on China’s export boom.6
In particular, quotas on the Multi-Fibre Agreement were eliminated in two waves
in 2002 and 2005; according to Brambilla, Khandelwal, and Schott (2010), the
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
10 T. Doan et al.
removal of the quotas have led to a huge increase (270%) in Chinese textile and
apparel exports. Bloom,Draca, andVanReenen (2011, p.52) suggests that ‘China’s
[export] increase was substantially larger than other countries not just because it
joined the WTO but also because the existing quotas seemed to bite more heavily
on China as indicated by the higher “fill rates – the proportion of actual imports
divided by the quota” of Chinese quotas and Chinese quotas were increased more
slowly over time than those in other countries.’
Vietnam’s increasing import share from China seems to be exogenous to
Vietnamese firm productivity and determined by the fast-growing export of China
to the world in 2000s (see Appendices 1 and 2). To capture the shocks to Vietnam’s
imports by China’s accession to the WTO and the impact of the quota removal
for China in 2002 and 2005 and the China–ASEAN FTA in 2005, we can use the
change in China’s exports to instrument change in Vietnam’s import penetration.
As a further means of limiting the potential bias from endogeneity of import
penetration, we use lagged rather than current values of import penetration and IV
methods. Longer period lags of the import penetration variablesmay be appropriate
as import penetration would take time to have an effect on local firm productivity.
However, using long changes restricts the sample as a result of dropping initial
periods, and also excluding short-lived firms. The latter may lead to survivor bias –
by estimating impact on only surviving firms, we would miss out possible negative
impacts of import penetration on short-lived firms.
We estimate Equation 5 in time-differenced specifications – regressing changes
in the logarithm of firm value added against changes in log of factor inputs
and (lagged) import penetration. The differencing removes industry and firm-
level variation in the level of productivity, and the bias associated with import
penetration. We present estimates using changes over two or three years. Estimates
based on longer changes better capture the impact of more persistent changes, and
are less affected by noise that biases the coefficients towards zero (Griliches
and Hausman 1986).7 The estimating equation is shown as Equation 5, with all
variables included as k-period changes, and import penetration variables lagged
by m periods. Lagged changes are used to ensure that import penetration changes
are predetermined relative to current plan productivity changes, and to allow for
the possibility that the effect on productivity may take time to have an effect. We
then combine level and time-differences with the IV method to further consolidate
our findings.
k lnVAijt = α + β1kimp penj,t−m + β2k lnKijt
+β3k lnLijt + β4ownershipij t + λt + eijt (5)
Equation (5) is estimated with standard errors clustered by industry and year to
allow for the fact that measured import penetration does not vary within industry
and year (Moulton 1990).8
We also want to test the hypothesis that import competition may affect various
groups of firms differently, e.g. comparedwith high-tech firms, but the competition
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 11
from Chinese imports may adversely affect the outcomes of low-tech industries
(firms), such that low-tech firms shrink or even exit, with consequent reduction in
employment. Firm size could be a proxy for firm competitiveness so that we will
run separate regressions for different firm size groups. We expect that larger firms
are more likely to compete with imports while smaller firms may be crowded out
by cheaper and better (to some extent) quality products from imports.We therefore
estimate the effects of import penetration for different firm sizes and for various
technology level industries.
4. Empirical results
4.1. Baseline effect estimates
The first and second columns of Table 2 present the results of OLS and FE
estimation of Equation (1), which models the log of value added as a function of
the log of contemporaneous factor inputs and import penetration. The estimates
of Equation (2) are shown in columns 3, 4 and 5 of Table 2, modelling changes in
the log of value added on contemporaneous (k = 0) changes in the log of inputs
and penetration, for changes over two and three years.
The coefficients for both labour input and the cost of capital services are highly
significant across the models, and provide credible production function estimates.
The OLS estimates are likely to be upward biased due to the correlation of factor
inputs with firm fixed effects. The implied increasing returns to scale coefficient
(the sum of labour and capital coefficients) is 1.08. This reduces to 1.02 when
fixed effects are controlled for in column 2, and lies between 0.86 and 1.02 in the
differenced specification. The lowest estimate of 0.86 is for the second differenced
specification, in which coefficients, especially the coefficient on labour, is lower
due to transitory fluctuations. All the models are controlled for industry, year and
ownership (foreign, state and private) dummies.
The inclusion of concurrent import penetration variables in Table 2 may result
in endogeneity bias, but they provide baseline estimates and also some evidence
of self-selection of import penetration. For example, industries with lower pro-
ductivity tend to import more. All regressions include industry and year effects,
so that the estimated impact of import penetration reflects the association between
changes in productivity and changes in penetration over time within an industry.
The FE estimate of import penetration in the second column of Table 2 is
smaller (in absolute terms) than that of the OLS estimation. The estimates across
differenced specifications are also lower than the OLS estimate. The variation
in the coefficient across these specifications reflects a combination of different
samples and the potential impact of endogeneity associated with using concurrent
changes of import penetration. Sample sizes are smaller when using longer time-
differences because the data excludes short-lived firms.
To remove endogeneity bias and reduce the influence of volatile short-term
fluctuations, our preferred specification for time differences relies on lagged values
of import penetration changes, as in Equation (5), with changes measured over two
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
12 T. Doan et al.
Ta
bl
e
2.
E
ff
ec
ts
of
im
po
rt
pe
ne
tr
at
io
n
on
fi
rm
pr
od
uc
tiv
it
y,
20
00
–2
00
9.
Tw
o-
ye
ar
Tw
o-
ye
ar
T
hr
ee
-y
ea
r
C
on
tr
ol
le
d
O
L
S
Fi
xe
d
ef
fe
ct
di
ff
er
en
ce
di
ff
er
en
ce
di
ff
er
en
ce
fo
r
te
ch
H
ig
h
te
ch
V
ar
ia
bl
es
(k
=
0)
(1
)
(k
=
0)
(2
)
(k
=
2)
(3
)
(k
=
2)
(4
)
(k
=
3)
(5
)
le
ve
l(
6)
on
ly
(7
)
kl
nL
t
0.
69
8
0.
68
0
0.
65
3
0.
55
5
0.
68
0
0.
55
5
0.
64
9
(0
.0
06
)∗
(0
.0
23
)∗
(0
.0
11
)∗
(0
.0
15
)∗
(0
.0
12
)∗
(0
.0
15
)∗
(0
.0
38
)∗
kl
nK
t
0.
37
8
0.
33
6
0.
33
3
0.
30
5
0.
33
6
0.
31
0
0.
28
5
(0
.0
05
)∗
(0
.0
12
)∗
(0
.0
06
)∗
(0
.0
08
)∗
(0
.0
07
)∗
(0
.0
08
)∗
(0
.0
18
)∗
kI
m
p_
pe
n t
–0
.0
61
–0
.0
20
–0
.0
35
–0
.0
16
(0
.0
05
)∗
(0
.0
02
)∗
(0
.0
02
)∗
(0
.0
02
)∗
kI
m
p_
pe
n t
-3
–0
.0
16
–0
.0
16
1
–0
.0
14
7
(0
.0
02
)∗
(0
.0
02
)∗
(0
.0
02
)∗
C
on
st
an
t
1.
81
6
1.
97
2
0.
10
8
0.
13
5
0.
14
8
0.
13
5
0.
04
87
(0
.0
47
)∗
(0
.0
74
)∗
(0
.0
22
)∗
(0
.0
29
)∗
(0
.0
27
)∗
(0
.0
29
)∗
(0
.1
15
9)
O
bs
er
va
ti
on
s
19
1,
90
7
19
1,
90
7
88
,7
97
32
,2
14
64
,9
56
32
,2
14
32
27
R
-s
qu
ar
ed
0.
87
(w
)0
.5
7
0.
39
0.
29
0.
45
0.
29
0.
32
Y
ea
r
ef
fe
ct
Y
es
Y
es
Y
es
Y
es
Y
es
Y
es
Y
es
In
d2
co
nt
ro
ll
ed
Y
es
N
o
Y
es
Y
es
Y
es
Y
es
Y
es
N
ot
e:
T
he
de
pe
nd
en
t
va
ri
ab
le
is
th
e
na
tu
ra
l
lo
g
of
va
lu
e
ad
de
d.
C
lu
st
er
ed
(b
y
ye
ar
an
d
in
d4
)
st
an
da
rd
er
ro
rs
ar
e
in
pa
re
nt
he
se
s.
∗ s
ig
ni
fi
ca
nt
at
1%
.k
re
pr
es
en
ts
ti
m
e
le
ng
th
-d
if
fe
re
nc
es
;‘
k
=
0’
in
di
ca
te
s
le
ve
ls
.A
ll
m
od
el
s
co
nt
ro
lf
or
ye
ar
,t
w
o-
di
gi
ti
nd
us
tr
y
du
m
m
ie
s
an
d
ow
ne
rs
hi
p
(p
ri
va
te
,S
O
E
s
an
d
F
D
I)
.
k
is
k-
ye
ar
di
ff
er
en
ce
s.
S
w
it
ch
in
g
in
du
st
ry
w
as
co
rr
ec
te
d
to
al
lo
w
fo
r
fi
xe
d
ef
fe
ct
w
it
hi
n
in
du
st
ry
(i
nd
4)
an
d
al
so
co
rr
ec
tly
cl
us
te
ri
ng
.
Te
ch
le
ve
ls
ar
e
lo
w
,m
ed
iu
m
an
d
hi
gh
te
ch
no
lo
gy
.
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 13
years (column 4 of Table 2). Lag lengths are used to ensure that lagged changes
are measured prior to output changes.
Estimates of our preferred specification are shown in column 4 of Table 2. As
we use two-year differences, the shortest pre-determined lag of import penetration
variables that we can use is a three-period lag. One of the costs of ensuring that
import penetration variables are pre-determined is that the estimation sample is
greatly reduced due to the absence of lagged values for early years. The estimation
sample is reduced to 32,214, which is about one-third of the sample available for
the two-year differenced specification in column 3 of Table 2.
The first column of Table 2 presents our baseline estimates. Changes in import
penetration are estimated to have a statistically significant and negative impact on
domestic firm productivity. The coefficient of negative 0.061 implies that across
all industries an increase of one per cent in import penetration lowers productivity
by 0.061%.
The estimated impact of penetration remains negative and significant when we
move to FE and time-differenced specifications. Although the time-differenced
specifications and distributed lag of import penetration remove a bulk of short-
lived firms, the effect is still negative and statistically significant but the magnitude
(in absolute terms) declines. This may imply that the effect of import penetration
is either overestimated by the OLS or stronger for short-lived firms.
The last two columns of Table 2 offer estimates from a model that controlled
for technology level dummies (column 6) and a model for high tech industries
only (column 7, see Appendix 3 for the definition of industry technological level).
The results in columns 6 and 7 are comparable with those in column 4. The results
from a model controlled for technology level are almost unchanged compared
with those in column 4. The results in column 7 for high tech industries only show
a slight change with the impact of import penetration reduced (in absolute terms)
marginally, from negative 0.016 to negative 0.015. The contribution of labour input
increases while that of capital declines in comparison with results in columns 4
and 6. This can be explained by the fact that the high technological industries
employ higher skilled workers and then labour input plays a more important role
in the firms’ output. However, the difference between the estimated coefficients of
the import penetration variable from high technological industries is very small
(0.001)) suggesting that the technology level does not matter in this case.
Because of similar or even lower level of Vietnam’s technological advancement
in relation to countries exporting to Vietnam, rising import penetration may lead
to fiercer competition among firms in Vietnam. Therefore, firms in Vietnam do
not have an advantage to cut costs or to innovate in order to improve efficiency or
to escape competition.
4.2. Instrumental variable approach
The other approach to correct for endogeneity of import penetration is to use an
IV method. As discussed earlier, China’s exports (or export growth) are a potential
instrument for the prediction of the level of Vietnam’s imports, but may not
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
14 T. Doan et al.
directly affect firms’ productivity in Vietnam. We thus make use of China’s export
penetration, the proportion of China’s exports over total sales of an industry, as an
instrument for import penetration. We apply the IV approach to both level variable
specifications (the left panel of Table 3) and time-differenced specifications (the
right panel of Table 3). We report some statistics for the relevance, validity and
weak IV tests on the bottom rows of Table 3.
All the test results in Table 3 show that the instrument is valid and strong,
implying that the instrument is good. The result from the IV approach is consistent
with the existing evidence in the literature which finds that China’s exports were
a good instrument to predict imports (Edwards and Jenkins 2013; Bloom, Draca,
and Van Reenen 2011; Bugamelli, Fabiani, and Sette 2010) and in line with the
theory of trade shocks from China’s export boom.
The left panel of Table 3 presents the estimated effects of import penetration
on firm productivity using level data. Three model specifications are investigated:
contemporaneous, the first lag and second lag of import penetration. The endoge-
nous variable, import penetration were instrumented by the corresponding Chinese
export penetration. The Anderson and Robin (AR) test for weak instrument rejects
the hypothesis of the weak instrument in all model specifications at the one per
cent level. The results in columns 2 and 3 are more statistically significant, in other
words, the estimated results in columns 2 and 3 are more precisely estimated (see
the last row of Table 3 for the test statistics).
The right panel of Table 3 combines three approaches, IV, time-difference
and lagged level of the difference. This combination can simultaneously address
omitted variable and endogeneity bias. The AR test statistics show even more
precise estimates especially in columns 4 and 6. The estimates are also smaller
(in absolute terms) than those from the left panel. However, it must be noted
that the sample size in the right panel is smaller than the ones in the left panel.
Consequently, we infer that the decline in the estimated effect is due to the removal
of short-lived firms from the sample.
Columns 7 and 8 of Table 3 offer estimates from a model that controlled
for technology level dummies (column 7) and a model for high technological
industries only (column 8). The results on columns 7 and 8 are comparable with
those in column 6. The results in both columns 7 and 8 are again almost unchanged
compared to that in column 6. In addition, the results are similar to those of
time-differenced specification models. This suggests that the impact of import
penetration on productivity does not vary across different technological levels.
Overall, the estimated results show that import penetration has a statistically
significant and negative effect on firm productivity. However, the magnitude of
the estimated coefficient of import penetration is relatively small compared to the
coefficients of the capital and labour variables. The estimated coefficient of minus
0.016 implies that an increase in import penetration equivalent to 1% of industry
output is estimated to decrease domestic firm productivity by 0.016%. This is
small. It therefore can be concluded that the rising import penetration does not
affect firm productivity to any significant economic extent.
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 15
Ta
bl
e
3.
E
ff
ec
ts
of
im
po
rt
pe
ne
tr
at
io
n
on
fi
rm
pr
od
uc
tiv
it
y,
20
00
–2
00
9
(I
V
es
ti
m
at
io
n–
G
M
M
m
et
ho
d)
.
K
=
0
(l
ev
el
)
K
=
2
(t
w
o-
ye
ar
di
ff
er
en
ce
)
V
ar
ia
bl
es
(1
)
(2
)
(3
)
(4
)
(5
)
(6
)
(7
)
(8
)
kl
nL
t
0.
69
8
0.
68
4
0.
67
7
0.
65
3
0.
57
8
0.
55
5
0.
55
5
0.
64
9
(0
.0
06
)∗
∗
(0
.0
06
)∗
∗
(0
.0
07
)∗
∗
(0
.0
11
)∗
∗
(0
.0
12
)∗
∗
(0
.0
15
)∗
∗
(0
.0
15
)∗
∗
(0
.0
38
)∗
∗
kl
nK
t
0.
37
8
0.
39
0
0.
40
1
0.
33
3
0.
30
1
0.
30
5
0.
30
5
0.
28
5
(0
.0
05
)∗
∗
(0
.0
06
)∗
∗
(0
.0
06
)∗
∗
(0
.0
06
)∗
∗
(0
.0
07
)∗
∗
(0
.0
08
)∗
∗
(0
.0
08
1)
∗∗
(0
.0
18
)∗
∗
ki
m
p_
pe
n
–0
.0
91
–0
.0
35
(0
.0
41
)∗
(0
.0
03
)∗
∗
ki
m
p_
pe
n_
L
1
–0
.0
67
–0
.0
14
(0
.0
18
)∗
∗
(0
.0
04
)∗
∗
ki
m
p_
pe
n_
L
2
–0
.0
25
(0
.0
07
)∗
∗
ki
m
p_
pe
n_
L
3
–0
.0
16
–0
.0
16
–0
.0
15
(0
.0
03
)∗
∗
(0
.0
03
)∗
∗
(0
.0
02
5)
∗∗
co
ns
ta
nt
1.
81
6
1.
88
5
1.
95
2
0.
07
1
0.
11
5
0.
13
5
0.
27
2
0.
06
0
(0
.0
47
)∗
∗
(0
.0
38
)∗
∗
(0
.0
36
)∗
∗
(0
.0
24
)∗
∗
(0
.0
19
)∗
∗
(0
.0
29
)∗
∗
(0
.0
24
)∗
∗
(0
.0
12
)∗
∗
O
bs
er
va
ti
on
s
19
1,
90
7
12
9,
27
4
95
,3
82
88
,7
97
62
,6
89
32
,2
14
32
,2
14
32
27
C
en
tr
ed
R
2
0.
87
0.
89
0.
89
0.
39
0.
30
0.
29
0.
29
0.
32
In
st
ru
m
en
te
d
va
ri
ab
le
im
p_
pe
n
im
p_
pe
n_
L
1
im
p_
pe
n_
L
2
2
im
p_
pe
n
2
im
p_
pe
n_
L
1
2
im
p_
pe
n_
L
3
2
im
p_
pe
n_
L
3
2
im
p_
pe
n_
L
3
E
xc
lu
de
d
ex
pC
N
_p
en
ex
p
ex
p
2
ex
p
2
ex
p
2
ex
p
2
ex
p
2
ex
p
in
st
ru
m
en
t
C
N
_p
en
_L
1
C
N
_p
en
_L
2
C
N
_p
en
C
N
_p
en
_L
1
C
N
_p
en
_L
3
C
N
_p
en
_L
3
C
N
_p
en
_L
3
1s
ts
ta
ge
P
ro
b
>
F
0.
00
00
0.
00
00
0.
00
00
0.
00
00
0.
00
00
0.
00
00
0.
00
00
0.
00
00
Pa
rt
ia
lR
2
0.
93
0.
98
0.
98
0.
99
0.
99
0.
99
0.
99
0.
98
Te
st
fo
r
in
st
ru
m
en
t
2.
6e
+
06
6.
7e
+
06
9.
2e
+
06
1.
2e
+
07
7.
5e
+
06
1.
2e
+
07
1.
2e
+
07
3.
4e
+
07
eq
ua
lz
er
o
in
th
e
(0
.0
00
0)
(0
.0
00
0)
(0
.0
00
0)
(0
.0
00
0)
(0
.0
00
0)
(0
.0
00
0)
(0
.0
00
0)
(0
.0
00
0)
1s
ts
ta
ge
,F
-v
al
(P
-v
al
)
A
R
te
st
fo
r
w
ea
k
IV
,
7.
96
∗∗
15
.5
6∗
∗
11
.9
9∗
∗
13
9.
43
∗∗
8.
86
∗∗
39
.9
∗∗
39
.8
∗∗
36
.5
∗∗
C
hi
2(
1)
(P
-v
al
ue
(0
.0
04
8)
(0
.0
00
1)
(0
.0
00
5)
(0
.0
00
0)
(0
.0
02
9)
(0
.0
00
0)
(0
.0
00
0)
(0
.0
00
0)
in
br
ac
ke
t)
N
ot
e:
T
he
de
pe
nd
en
tv
ar
ia
bl
e
is
th
e
na
tu
ra
ll
og
of
va
lu
e
ad
de
d.
C
lu
st
er
ed
(b
y
ye
ar
an
d
in
du
st
ry
)
st
an
da
rd
er
ro
rs
ar
e
in
pa
re
nt
he
se
s.
∗ s
ig
ni
fi
ca
nt
at
5%
;a
nd
∗∗
at
1%
.
k
re
pr
es
en
ts
ti
m
e
le
ng
th
-d
if
fe
re
nc
es
;‘
k
=
0’
in
di
ca
te
s
k-
ye
ar
-d
if
fe
re
nc
e.
L
is
la
g
le
ve
l.
A
ll
m
od
el
s
co
nt
ro
ll
ed
fo
r
ye
ar
,t
w
o-
di
gi
ti
nd
us
tr
y
fi
xe
d
ef
fe
ct
an
d
ow
ne
rs
hi
p
(p
ri
va
te
,S
O
E
s
an
d
F
D
I)
.C
ol
um
n
7
co
nt
ro
ll
ed
fo
r
te
ch
le
ve
ld
um
m
ie
s,
an
d
co
lu
m
n
8
is
fo
r
hi
gh
te
ch
in
du
st
ri
es
on
ly
.
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
16 T. Doan et al.
Table 4. Decomposing effects by firm size (employees), 2000–2009.
Firm size fewer than Firm size greater than or equal
20 100 200 200
Variable (1) (2) (3) (4)
2lnLt 0.588 0.552 0.553 0.560
(0.027)∗∗ (0.017)∗∗ (0.015)∗∗ (0.030)∗∗
2lnKt 0.325 0.311 0.310 0.285
(0.014)∗∗ (0.009)∗∗ (0.009)∗∗ (0.016)∗∗
2Imp_pent-3 –0.018 –0.013 –0.013 46.691
(0.004)∗∗ (0.002)∗∗ (0.002)∗∗ (25.086)
Constant 0.371 0.081 0.084 0.183
(0.279) (0.041)∗ (0.034)∗ (0.056)∗∗
Observations 8032 19693 23947 8267
R-squared 0.30 0.30 0.30 0.26
Note: The dependent variable is the two-year difference in the log of value added. Clustered standard
errors are in parentheses; ∗significant at 5%; ∗∗significant at 1%. Dependant variable 2lnva, 2 is
the two-year difference. All models controlled for year, two-digit industry fixed effect and ownership
(private, SOEs and FDI).
4.3. Effects by firm size
Firms may have different competitive capacity to compete with imports. The liter-
ature on import competition suggests that firms with less advanced technologies
or small firms may find it hard to compete with imports (e.g. Bloom, Draca, and
Van Reenen 2011; Bugamelli, Fabiani, and Sette 2010). In this section, we hypoth-
esize that larger domestic firms may benefit more from the presence of increasing
imports, due to their generally more sophisticated technologies and business pro-
cesses, while smaller firms suffer a negative crowding out effect from intensifying
import competition. The estimates are presented in the first two columns of Table 4.
We use three cut-offs: 20, 100 and 200 employees to classify firms.
Our estimates show that the coefficients are more negative for smaller groups.
However, the estimated coefficients for subsample in columns 1, 2 and 3 are small
so that the difference between coefficients in these columns is negligible. In the
meantime, the effect is positive for firms with 200 or more employees, but the
effect is not estimated precisely, i.e. not statistically significant at the five per cent
level.
4.4. Impact of increased import penetration on the likelihood
of firm death
We now look at the effects of rising import penetration on firm survival that have
not been captured by the main estimates earlier. Firms that cease operation within
two years of a change in import penetration are automatically excluded from the
estimating sample. The bias from excluding ceased firms will depend on whether
the firm death is raised or lowered and on whether the affected firms have high
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 17
Ta
bl
e
5.
Im
pa
ct
of
in
cr
ea
se
d
im
po
rt
pe
ne
tr
at
io
n
on
th
e
li
ke
li
ho
od
of
fi
rm
de
at
h.
Tw
o-
ye
ar
di
ff
er
en
ce
(k
=
2)
T
hr
ee
-y
ea
r
di
ff
er
en
ce
(k
=
3)
(1
)
(2
)
(3
)
(4
)
(5
)
(6
)
kl
nL
t
–0
.0
41
6
–0
.0
61
9
–0
.0
90
7
–0
.0
48
8
–0
.0
84
2
–0
.0
81
9
(0
.0
03
0)
∗∗
(0
.0
04
1)
∗∗
(0
.0
10
7)
∗∗
(0
.0
03
4)
∗∗
(0
.0
06
3)
∗∗
(0
.0
09
0)
∗∗
kl
nK
t
–0
.0
15
7
–0
.0
24
4
–0
.0
38
4
–0
.0
17
2
–0
.0
30
0
–0
.0
36
8
(0
.0
02
0)
∗∗
(0
.0
02
3)
∗∗
(0
.0
05
7)
∗∗
(0
.0
02
1)
∗∗
(0
.0
03
8)
∗∗
(0
.0
05
1)
∗∗
Fo
re
ig
n
–0
.1
49
8
–0
.1
19
4
–0
.0
64
2
–0
.1
12
8
–0
.1
11
1
–0
.0
66
8
(0
.0
13
2)
∗∗
(0
.0
13
5)
∗∗
(0
.0
28
0)
∗
(0
.0
13
4)
∗∗
(0
.0
21
8)
∗∗
(0
.0
28
1)
∗
P
ri
va
te
0.
06
78
0.
09
27
0.
23
11
0.
10
21
0.
17
64
0.
23
32
(0
.0
13
2)
∗∗
(0
.0
13
7)
∗∗
(0
.0
26
6)
∗∗
(0
.0
13
5)
∗∗
(0
.0
21
7)
∗∗
(0
.0
26
2)
∗∗
ki
m
p_
pe
n t
0.
03
86
0.
04
45
(0
.0
11
4)
∗∗
(0
.0
10
9)
∗∗
ki
m
p_
pe
n_
L
1
0.
62
76
5.
10
52
(4
.4
29
0)
(1
0.
93
12
)
ki
m
p_
pe
n_
L
3
4.
79
24
1.
54
33
(1
6.
31
91
)
(2
1.
91
77
)
O
bs
er
va
ti
on
s
63
,4
24
42
,9
71
11
,0
16
44
,3
56
20
,2
85
11
,0
75
W
al
d
ch
i2
36
97
.5
7
33
03
.4
2
n/
a
35
06
.4
31
86
.1
6
46
07
6.
25
P
ro
b
>
ch
i2
0.
00
00
0.
00
00
0.
00
00
0.
00
00
0.
00
00
0.
00
00
N
ot
e:
T
he
re
su
lt
s
sh
ow
n
ar
e
av
er
ag
e
m
ar
gi
na
l
ef
fe
ct
s
es
ti
m
at
ed
fr
om
P
ro
bi
t
m
od
el
s.
T
he
de
pe
nd
en
t
va
ri
ab
le
is
an
in
di
ca
to
r
of
w
he
th
er
th
e
fi
rm
ce
as
es
to
op
er
at
e
w
it
hi
n
th
e
fo
ll
ow
in
g
th
re
e
ye
ar
s.
It
ta
ke
s
th
e
va
lu
e
of
1
fo
r
th
re
e
ye
ar
s
pr
io
r
to
th
e
de
at
h
of
a
fi
rm
,a
nd
0
ot
he
rw
is
e.
R
ob
us
t
cl
us
te
re
d
st
an
da
rd
er
ro
rs
ar
e
gi
ve
n
in
pa
re
nt
he
se
s;
∗ s
ig
ni
fi
ca
nt
at
5%
;
∗∗
si
gn
ifi
ca
nt
at
1%
.
T
he
sa
m
pl
e
is
re
st
ri
ct
ed
to
20
00
–2
00
7
so
th
at
ea
ch
fi
rm
’s
su
rv
iv
al
ca
n
be
ob
se
rv
ed
fo
r
th
e
fo
ll
ow
in
g
th
re
e
ye
ar
s.
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
18 T. Doan et al.
or low productivity levels. If the rising import penetration raises the probability
that local firms with slow productivity growth cease operation, this may lead to
survivor bias – by estimating impact on only surviving firms, we would miss out
possible negative impacts of rising import penetration on ceased firms.
In order to gauge the possible impact of rising import penetration on firm
survival, we estimate the probability of firms ceasing operation as a function of
changes in import penetration. In order to focus on the subset of firms potentially
excluded by our main specification, we estimate a firm’s likelihood of ceasing
operation within three years, following a two-year change in import penetration.9
Table 5 presents estimates from a Probit regression of firm death, with estimates
reported as (average) marginal effects.
The positive coefficients on all model specifications of import penetration
change imply that increases in import penetration raise the probability of firm
death, though the estimated effect is statistically significant only for columns 1
and 4 (Table 5). The positive coefficient implies that rising import penetration
raises the probability of firm death within three years.
The columns 2, 3, 5 and 6 of Table 5 show whether changes in import pene-
tration affect firm survival over a longer time period. As in Table 5, the inclusion
of longer lags has the effect of restricting the sample to firms that have been
operating for longer than three years. As the sample size reduces considerably, the
estimates become less precise, but the signs of coefficients are still positive. The
signs of other variables are as expected: larger firms (more employment and capi-
tal) and foreign owned firms are more likely to survive, ceteris paribus. Overall,
we observe that increasing import competition raises the likelihood of firm death.
5. Conclusion and discussion
This paper examines how firm productivity is affected by rising import penetra-
tion in the Vietnam manufacturing sector. The analysis employs a panel data-set
of more than 200,000 firms during the period 2000–2009, thus making the sample
comprehensive and representative of the Vietnam manufacturing business popu-
lation. The source of the data was the VES from the Vietnam General Statistics
Office. The study uses different approaches to deal with biases caused by omitted
variables and the endogeneity of import penetration.
Overall, as we set out in the beginning of the paper, Vietnamese manufacturing
firms are typically less technologically advanced and have low competitiveness.
We find that an increase of one per cent in import penetration results in a small
decline (0.016 per cent) in productivity. There is no evidence of a positive effect on
productivity from many robust estimates even our sample included only survival
firms.10 Our finding is consistent with Federico (2014), who find no positive effect
of import penetration from low-wage countries on firm employment, the wage bill
and outputs in Italy’s manufacturing firms those with low tech advancement, and
Alvarez and Claro (2008) who find no positive effect of rising import penetration
on firm productivity in Chilean manufacturing firms. Unlike most research on
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 19
developed countries, in Vietnam as well as in Chile capital and skilled labours
are scarce, which impedes or makes it costly for product upgrading. Moreover,
imports displace or crowd out domestic production (Edwards and Jenkins 2013).
This may cause local firms to lose market shares to importing firms, thus reducing
their scale of production which impacts negatively on productivity. Firms lose
their scale efficiency.
Firms’ exposure to increasing import competition leads to lower productivity,
but this is economically small. The small negative impact is mainly from smaller
firm groups, who have 200 or fewer employees. We also find some evidence of
positive effects for larger firm groups, but the effects are less precisely estimated.
In addition, we do not find any significant evidence of variation in the impact of
import penetration across different technological level industries, but we observe
some evidence of positive effects of increased import penetration on the likelihood
of firm death.
In future research, we would refine our study by separating out imports from
developing and developed countries. We also would separate various impacts
of imported inputs by classifying imported intermediate inputs and imports of
final competing goods to see how they affect firm performance in developing
economies. Furthermore, as suggested by Yahmed and Dougherty (2012), one
may look at the position of firm’s productivity in relation to the industry produc-
tivity frontier to provide a better measure of technological advance. In addition,
considering multiple product or multiple business functionality firms (e.g. firms
both import inputs and/or complete products for sales and produce products for
local and exporting markets), the effect of import penetration would vary across
different types of firms (Bernard, Redding and Schott 2011). Finally, the net benefit
of trade liberalization can be observed when we look at the impacts of imports, ex-
ports and across-industry effect simultaneously. This is another avenue for future
research.
Acknowledgements
We thank, without implicating, two anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments and
suggestions to improve the paper. Any remaining errors in the paper are those of the authors.
Disclosure statement
No potential conflict of interest was reported by the authors.
Notes
1.
2. The concording program is available upon request.
3. In Vietnam, it is not unusual to run a business before having a tax code.
4. But longer time differencing, e.g. three-year or four-year differencing also comes
at the cost of losing more observations of short-lived firms;therefore, two-year
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
20 T. Doan et al.
differenced specification is the main model specification for our time-differencing
approach.
5. The Agreement on Trade in Goods of the China–ASEAN FTA entered into force in
July 2005, and the Agreement on Trade in Services came into effect in July 2007.
6. Bloom, Draca, and Van Reenen (2011, p.28) indicate that China is a good experiment
of low-wage country trade shock in the recent decades.
7. For this reason, we do not estimate for one-year difference specification.
8. Clustering may be still problematic if the number of clusters (industry-years) is small
relative to the number of units per cluster. Cameron, Gelbach, and Miller (2008)
suggest cluster bootstrapping techniques for inference. We tried both clustered and
clustered bootstrapping for our main estimates and found similar estimated standard
errors. We report clustered standard errors in the paper.
9. Firm survival cannot be accurately identified by a firm’s absence from our analysis
data alone. A firm is classified as continuing if, in the following year, there is output or
intermediate input recorded in the VES data-set, if the firm has positive employment
or if any sales or purchases are observed.
10. If including exited firms in the sample, the estimated effect would be more negative,
but obviously not positive as exited firms should be the least productive ones. Our
estimated effect thus would be underestimated.
References
Acharya, R.C., and W. Keller. 2009. “Technology Transfer Through Imports.” Canadian
Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne D’e´conomique 42 (4): 1411–1448.
Ackerberg, D., K. Caves, and G. Frazer. 2006. “Structural Identification of Production
Functions.”
Aghion, P., N. Bloom, R. Blundell, R. Griffith, and P. Howitt. 2005. “Competition and
Innovation: An Inverted-U Relationship.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 120 (2):
701–728.
Aghion, P., S. Redding, R. Burgess, and F. Zilibotti. 2005. “Entry Liberalization and
Inequality in Industrial Performance.” Journal of European Economic Association 3
(2–3): 291–302.
Altenburg, L., and A. Brenken. 2008. “Effort, Trade, and Unemployment.” Canadian
Journal of Economics 41 (3): 864–893.
Alvarez, R., and Claro S. 2008. “David Versus Goliath: The Impact of Chinese Competition
on Developing Countries.” World Development 37 (3): 560–571.
Amiti, M., and J. Konings. 2007. “Trade Liberalization, Intermediate Inputs, and Produc-
tivity: Evidence From Indonesia.” American Economic Review 97 (5): 1611—1638.
Autor, D., D. Dorn, and G. Hanson. 2013. “The China Syndrome: Local Labour Market
Effects of Import Competition in the United States.” American Economic Review
103 (6): 2121–2168.
Bernard, A., S. Redding, and P. Schott. 2011. “Multi-Product Firms and Trade Liberaliza-
tion.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126 (3): 1271–1318.
Bloom, N., M. Draca, and J. Van Reenen. 2011. Trade Induced Technical Change? The
Impact of Chinese Imports on Innovation, IT and Productivity. National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Brambilla, I., A.K. Khandelwal, and P.K. Schott. 2010. “China’s Experience Under the
Multi-Fiber Arrangement (MFA) and the Agreement on Textiles and Clothing (ATC).”
In China’s Growing Role in World Trade, edited by R. Feenstra and Sh. Wei, 345–387.
University of Chicago Press.
Bugamelli, M., S. Fabiani, and E. Sette. 2010. “The Pro-Competitive Effect of Imports
from China: An Analysis of Firm-Level Price Data.” Working Paper No. 737. Rome:
Bank of Italy.
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 21
Cameron, A., B. Gelbach, and L. Miller. 2008. “Bootstrap-Based Improvements for Infer-
ence with Clustered Errors.” Review of Economics and Statistics 90 (3): 414–427.
Coe, D.T., and E. Helpman. 1995. “International R&D Spillovers.” European Economic
Review 39 (5): 859–887.
Doan, T., and P. Stevens. 2012. “Evolution of Competition in Vietnam Industries over
the Recent Economic Transition.” Economics – The Open-Access, Open-Assessment
E-Journal 6 (19): 1–24.
Edwards, L., and R. Jenkins. 2013. The Impact of Chinese Import Penetration on
the South African Manufacturing Sector. https://www.uea.ac.uk/documents/439774/
0/Edwards+ Jenjkins+SALDRU.pdf/82f05bfc-bf8b-4af1-b843-bb522695c6d6
Federico, S. 2014. “Industry Dynamics and Competition from Low-Wage Countries: Evi-
dence from Italy.” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 76 (3): 389–410.
Fernandes, A. 2007. “Trade Policy, Trade Volumes and Plant-Level Productivity in Colom-
bian Manufacturing Industries.” Journal of International Economics 71 (1): 52–71.
Ferreira, P, and J. Rossi. 2003. “New Evidence from Brazil on Trade Liberalization and
Productivity Growth.” International Economic Review 44 (4): 1383–1405.
Freeman, R.B., and M.M. Kleiner. 2005. “The Last American Shoe Manufacturers: De-
creasing Productivity and Increasing Profits in the Shift from Piece Rates to Continuous
Flow Production.” Industrial Relations: A Journal of Economy and Society 44 (2): 307–
330.
Griliches, Z., and J. Hausman. 1986. “Errors in Variables in Panel Data.” Journal of Econo-
metrics 31 (1): 93–118.
Griliches, Z, and J.Mairesse. 1998. “ProductionFunctions: TheSearch for Identification.” In
Econometrics andEconomic Theory in the 20thCentury: TheRagnar FrischCentennial
Symposium, edited by S. Strøm, 169–203. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Grossman, G.M., and E. Helpman. 1995. “Technology and Trade.” Handbook of Interna-
tional Economics 3: 1279–1337.
Halpern, L., M. Koren, and A. Szeidl. 2005. Imports and Productivity.
ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id = 785127
Halpern, L., and G. Ko¨ro¨si. 2001. “Efficiency andMarket Share in the Hungarian Corporate
Sector.” Economics of Transition 9 (3): 559–592.
Holmes, T., and J. Schmitz. 2010. “Competition and Productivity: A Review of Evidence.”
Research Department Staff Report no. 439. Minneapolis: Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis.
Kasahara, H., and J. Rodrigue. 2008. “Does the Use of Imported Intermediates Increase
Productivity? Plant-Level Evidence.” Journal of Development Economics 87 (1): 106–
118.
Kumbhakar, S. 2003. “Factor Productivity and Technical Change.” Applied Economics
Letters 10 (5): 291–297.
Levinsohn, J. & A. Petrin. 2003. “Estimating Production Functions using Inputs to Control
for Unobservables.” Review of Economic Studies 70 (2): 317–41.
Melitz, M. 2003. “The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate
Industry Productivity.” Econometrica 71 (6): 1695–1725.
Mion, G., and L. Zhu. 2013. “Import Competition from and Offshoring to China: A Curse
or Blessing for Firms?” Journal of International Economics 89 (2013): 202–215.
Moulton, B.R. 1990. “An Illustration of a Pitfall in Estimating the Effects of Aggregate
Variables on Micro Units.” Review of Economics and Statistics 72 (2): 334–338.
Olley, G.S. and A. Pakes. 1996. “The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications
Equipment Industry.” Econometrica 64 (6): 1263–1297.
Pavcnik, N. 2002. “Trade Liberalization, Exit, and Productivity Improvements: Evidence
from Chilean Plants.” Review of Economic Studies 69 (1): 245–276.
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
22 T. Doan et al.
Sivadasan, J. 2009. “Barriers to Competition and Productivity: Evidence from India.” B.E.
Journal of Economic, Analysis and Policy 9 (1): 1–66.
Van Biesebroeck, J. 2003. Revisiting Some Productivity Debates. National Bureau of Eco-
nomic Research.
Vogel, A., and J. Wagner. 2010. “Higher Productivity in Importing German Manufacturing
Firms: Self-Selection, Learning from Importing, or Both?” Review of World Economics
145 (4): 641–665.
Vogel, A., and J.Wagner. 2011. Robust estimates of exporter productivity premia inGerman
business services enterprises. Working Paper Series in Economics 207, University of
Lu¨neburg, Institute of Economics.
Wooldridge, J. 2009. “On Estimating Firm-Level Production Functions Using Proxy Vari-
ables to Control for Unobservables.” Economics Letters 104 (2009): 112–114.
Yahmed, S., and S. Dougherty. 2012. “Import Competition, Domestic Regulation and Firm-
Level Productivity Growth in the OECD.” OECD, Economics Department Working
Paper No. 980. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.
Appendix 1: China export over time
Total world export CN export
Year ($US billion) ($US billion) Growth Note
1998 5158 184 1%
1999 5220 195 6%
2000 6010 249 28%
2001 5830 266 7% (WTO accession)
2002 6190 326 23%
2003 7240 438 34%
2004 8780 593 35%
2005 9940 762 28%
2006 11,600 969 27%
2007 13,200 1220 26%
2008 15,300 1430 17% GFC
2009 11,900 1200 –16% GFC
2010 14,400 1580 32%
2011 15,000 1900 20%
Average 10,047 808 19%
Source: UN Comtrade database
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 23
Appendix 2: Vietnam import from the world and China
VN import
Total VN import %VN from CN
VN import VN import from China import in (% in
Year ($US billion) growth ($US billion) world trade total import)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
1998 11.5 –0.9% 0.51 0.22% 4%
1999 11.7 1.7% 0.67 0.22% 6%
2000 15.6 33.3% 1.40 0.26% 9%
2001 16.2 3.8% 1.61 0.28% 10%
2002 19.7 21.6% 2.16 0.32% 11%
2003 25.3 28.4% 3.14 0.35% 12%
2004 32.0 26.5% 4.60 0.36% 14%
2005 36.8 15.0% 5.90 0.37% 16%
2006 44.9 22.0% 7.39 0.39% 16%
2007 62.8 39.9% 12.71 0.48% 20%
2008 80.7 28.5% 15.97 0.53% 20%
2009 69.9 –13.4% 15.41 0.59% 22%
2010 84.8 21.3% 20.20 0.59% 24%
2011 107.0 26.2% 24.59 0.71% 23%
Average 44.2 18% 8.3 0.41% 15%
Source: UN Comtrade and GSO website, column 3 is calculated from column 2 capturing nominal
growth rates.
Appendix 3: Tech level industry groups
Group 1: Low technology
D15: Food and beverages
D16: Cigarettes and tobacco
D17: Textile products
D18: Wearing apparel, dressing and dying of fur
D19: Leather and products of leather; leather substitutes; footwear.
D20: Wood and wood products, excluding furniture
D21: Paper and paper products
D22: Printing, publishing and reproduction of recorded media
D23: Coke and refined petroleum products and nuclear fuel
D36: Furniture and other products not classified elsewhere
D37: Recycles products
Group 2: Medium technology
D24: Chemicals and chemical products
D25: Rubber and plastic products
D26: Other non-metallic mineral products
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
24 T. Doan et al.
D27: Iron, steel and non-ferrous metal basic industries
D28: Fabricated metal products, except machinery and equipment
Group 3: High technology
D29: Machinery and equipment
D30: Computer and office equipment
D31: Electrical machinery apparatus, appliances and supplies
D32: Radios, television and telecommunication devices
D33: Medical equipment, optical instruments
D34: Motor vehicles and trailers
D35: Other transport equipment
D
ow
nl
oa
de
d
by
[D
r T
uy
en
T
ran
] a
t 0
6:2
9 2
1 M
ay
20
15
Các file đính kèm theo tài liệu này:
- does_rising_import_competition_harm_local_firm_productivity.pdf